“Passing back to the land”

Over the last few years, there has been a growing understanding that the cost of the affordable housing in inclusionary zoning (IZ) programs can be and is “passed back to the land”. In other words, it is being recognized that the cost burden (measured by difference between the market price or rent of these units and the reduced price or rent at which they must be provided) is substantially or entirely taken out of the price developers are willing to pay for land.

Developers typically determine the land value before making a purchase . To do so, they determine the potential revenue that can be obtained by one or more development schemes. From that they deduct the projected costs of development (for construction, loans, municipal fees and so on) as well as their anticipated profit (or return on investment). In this process, the affordable housing obligation is treated as another cost. The price that can be paid for the land is residual value left after the total costs are deducted from the revenue.

Predictability is critical for this to happen. The affordable housing obligation must be fixed in advance so that all developers are able to compete on a “level playing field” when bidding for the land. (Notably this does not happen in the case of s37 where the value of community benefits is determined by the negotiations over the development agreement, and so well after the land has been purchased.)

This process, it is recognized, raises a short-term problem. Developers already owning the land when these IZ provisions are passed will not be able to pass these costs back (unless they were able to anticipate the changes). As a consequence, these developers would be hit by the costs of the inclusionary obligation.

This problem can be addressed by exempting those projects already in the approval pipeline, and delaying – or, better yet, phasing in the affordable housing obligation – for some reasonable period (say, 3-5 years) after passing the inclusionary zoning by-law.

Burdening landowners in this way should not be seen as unwarranted or unfair. Landowners in high growth areas especially have benefitted enormously from rising “unearned” land values that they have done nothing to create. The municipalities, on the other hand, typically have a major hand in creating those land values through their investments in infrastructure and decisions over land-use and planning. So, IZ represents a way for municipalities to recover some part of that value that they helped to create but that otherwise would fall into private hands.

What the literature says

The literature on IZ frequently refers to this process. It is recognized by these leading authorities in the US:

• David Rosen (2016): “Regulation and development impact fees or residential development that increase the costs of development, including housing standards, will ultimately be passed through to the land owner in the form of reduced land prices.”

• Rick Jacobus (2015): “When a city imposes inclusionary housing requirements, … land prices will fall to absorb the costs of the inclusionary housing requirements.”

• Nico Calavita and Alan Mallach (2009): “There is little doubt that there are costs associated with complying with a municipality’s inclusionary requirement. … There seems to be agreement in the literature that in the long run … most of these costs will be passed backward to the owners of land.”

• Douglas Porter (2004): “Economists tend to argue that, in the long run, developers of projects subject to special development costs (such as impact fees and inclusionary requirements) will lower prices for developable land, since housing must be produced at competitive prices and rents the market will bear.”

• Nicholas Brunick (2003): “Basic economic theory suggests that an inclusionary set-aside, without providing cost offsets or incentives to cover the incremental cost of producing the affordable units, would cause developers to … pay less for land. … most of the economic literature indicates … that developers will most likely … bargain for a lower land price in order to profitably develop the housing. Thus, the theoretical incidence of an inclusionary zoning program (without sufficient cost offsets or incentives) over time, would be born by owners of land … (who) might see a reduced rate of appreciation in the values of their land over time. However, this moderate reduction in a rising real estate market is not likely to deprive these owners of earning a still, very healthy return on their investment.”

• Alan Mallach (1984): “There seems to be agreement in the literature that in the long run … most of the costs [of the affordable housing] will be passed backward to the owners of land.”

Even the Urban Land Institute, in a recent report (2016) that has been endorsed by the development industry, acknowledges the possibility of this process. It notes that “IZ may reduce what a developer can pay for land”. And “(when) IZ policies remain in place over a sustained period of time, land prices may adjust and the IZ requirements absorbed as a ‘cost of doing business’ in the jurisdiction”.

Who else could pay?

Other candidates for bearing the cost burden of the affordable units have been identified. These include the municipalities, developers and other homebuyers. But
the current evidence supports that none of these pay in any substantial way for the housing. So, this also indirectly bolsters the case for the cost burden falling back on the landowners.

Much of the key evidence comes from two studies (Furman 2007 and Smart Growth 2008) undertaken by non-partisan and university-based organizations. They independently collected and statistically analysed empirical data from a large sample of jurisdictions over a long period. Both came to the same basic conclusion: namely, that IZ has had little or no impact on the overall production or price of housing in the communities where it is used.

Homebuyers

Developers often take the position that they will simply pass on the cost burden associated with IZ to the other market buyers in the particular development. In turn, this will drive up the price of housing more generally. So, as a consequence, these programs essentially will require the other homebuyers to subsidize the affordable homebuyers.

The two authoritative studies refute this. They found that IZ had little or no impact on housing prices. The overall house prices in municipalities with inclusionary requirements were virtually the same those in municipalities without. And, if there was any increase attributable to IZ, it was insignificant when compared with the overall increase in market prices.

The reason for this is not difficult to understand. The price of housing is determined by the market as a whole – in a sort of tug-of-war between all developers and all buyers – and not by any individual developer on their own. Furthermore, it can be reasonably assumed that developers are already charging what they would consider to be the full market value for their product, and the homebuyers (especially, at the low-end-of-the-market) have already maxed out the price they can payit So, any cost burden imposed by IZ cannot be simply recovered from the other homebuyers through higher prices.

Developers sometimes also express this position by saying that homebuyers ultimately pay for everything – including not only the house itself, but also all of the government impositions like development charges, planning fees and inclusionary requirements. While true, there is a limit to what the homebuyer will bear and that is expressed through the market price. The job of the developers, if they want to stay in business, is to ensure that all of costs of development (along with their profits) somehow stay within that market price.

Developers

IZ programs are not, and cannot be, designed with the expectation that the developers will do so. Although the municipalities under IZ can require the provision of affordable housing as a condition of getting a development approval, they have no power to compel developers to build.

The developers have never expressed any willingness to absorb the cost burden. If the inclusionary obligation generates an unacceptable burden, developers will stop building, or at least delay building until the prices have risen sufficiently to make their profit.

But the empirical evidence shows that IZ does not impact overall housing production. While some developers might be adversely affected, municipalities with IZ programs produce housing more or less at the same volume as comparable municipalities without programs.

These findings indicate that developers are able to accommodate the affordable housing obligation, and to continue to build without significant damage to their viability. This is done by passing the cost burden back to the landowners

Municipalities

The role of the municipalities in assisting the provision of affordable housing in IZ programs is complicated. Most mandatory programs – but certainly by no means all – offer some form of compensation or other assistance. But that assistance is typically very limited in value and scope, or highly targeted when used more extensively.

Most offer a fixed and standard set of regulatory concessions in exchange for the affordable housing. These typically include relaxed regulations (for density, height, setbacks, parking, and others), waived fees and charges, and/or fast-tracked approvals.

But it is important to note there are also many successful programs that offer no assistance whatsoever. This is a clear indication that the provision of affordable housing under IZ is not dependent upon this help.

Also, in none of these programs do the concessions fully cover the cost burden. These concessions are best seen as token payments. They are given in the main because the municipalities consider unfair to impose costs and restrictions when the developers are being required to deliver housing at a lower price or rent. They are never calibrated to fit the needs of any particular development, nor provide a pre-determined level of assistance.

More extensive concessions are used in two particular and narrow circumstances:

• In voluntary (or incentive-based) programs, where unlike in mandatory programs, municipalities must fully re-imburse developers for the affordable housing provision in order to gain their participation. But once widely used, these programs have declined to a small minority because they have been proven to be unproductive.

• In negotiated and one-off agreements, where municipalities used additional forms of assistance to secure from selected developments (often non-profit) to reach greater affordability than possible under the standard and fixed provisions.

In both cases, municipalities have offered a wider range of assistance – like financial subsidies and property tax relief – that are rarely or never given to developers providing housing under the standard and fixed provisions. But the developments benefitting from this additional assistance represent a relatively portion of the total IZ developments. By not making the above distinctions, surveys tend to distort and inflate how the assistance is used in most common programs.

What does this mean for compensation?

If the cost burden can be passed back to land, it raises this question: why do municipalities need to provide concessions or any other assistance. It is not essential for effective programs. Unless done with care, this assistance will just sustain inflationary and values, and support the large unearned profits of the landowners.

Municipalities, after all, do have limited resources to provide for this assistance. Requiring them to provide significant assistance will actually undermine the productivity of these programs. This is because the lack of resources will limit the number of units and/or depth of affordability that can be supported by them.

There also is a downside to most or all of these concessions, and this in turn raises the question of how appropriate they are. For example, the waiving of fees could lead to a reduction in service levels, or higher fees for others. The use of density bonuses could result in bad planning by permitting higher density where not appropriate. The fast-track approvals for some could cause delays for others.

Municipalities should design programs in which developments providing the standard and fixed obligation receive no or little concessions. Their limited resources, instead, should be focussed on selected developments where they can effectively negotiate for deeper affordability in the form of additional affordable units and/or units serving lower incomes.

References

Vicki Been, et al.: “The Effects of Inclusionary Zoning on Local Housing Markets: Lessons from the San Francisco, Washington DC and Suburban Boston Areas”; Furman Center for Real Estate & Urban Policy, Working Paper 07-05, November 2007.

Gerrit-Jan Knaap, et al: “Housing Impacts of Inclusionary Zoning”; National Center for Smart Growth Research and Education; February 2008.

Nicholas Brunick: “The Impact of Inclusionary Zoning on Development”; Business and Professional People for the Public Interest; 2003.

Nico Calavita and Alan Mallach: “Inclusionary Housing, Incentives, and Land Value Recapture”; Land Lines, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy; January 2009.

David Paul Rosen & Associates: “Inclusionary Housing Study for the City of Portand”; November 2016.

Rick Jacobus: “ Inclusionary Housing – Creating and Maintaining Equitable Communities”; National Community Land Trust Network, Cornerstone Partnership and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy; 2015.

S. Williams, et al: “The Economics of Inclusionary Development”, The Urban Land Institute and Terwillinger Center for Housing, 2016.

Douglas R. Porter: “Inclusionary Zoning for Affordable Housing”; Urban Land Institute, 2004.

Alan Mallach: “Inclusionary Housing Programs: Policies and Practices”; Center for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers University, 1984.

Richard Drdla
27 Mar 2019

The Need for Compensation

Issue

The need for compensation in inclusionary zoning (IZ) remains a critical issue still to be resolved in Ontario. The basic question is this: does the success of IZ depend upon municipalities providing compensation – also known variously as contributions, concessions, incentives and cost offsets – to developers in return for the affordable housing.

Developers in Ontario have consistently and persistently called for ”municipal contributions” for the affordable units. For example, last August in the Toronto Star, the head of BILD wrote that the province’s IZ regulations were “all take and no give” by the municipalities. He then called again for a ‘partnership’, which is their coded way of referring to municipalities having to provide compensation. (Using this term in this way is peculiar to Ontario; there are no corresponding references to it anywhere in US.) (Wilkens 2018)

The draft Ontario regulations called for the municipalities to contribute towards 40% of the cost burden associated with the affordable housing. The municipalities were able to make these contributions only from certain regulatory concessions: namely, a waiver or reduction of planning application fees, parking requirements, parkland cash-in-lieu payments and/or development charges.

After pushback from the municipalities and affordable housing sector, this obligation was removed, but a new troubling one added. That regulation requires the municipalities to undertake a financial assessment of the “potential impacts on the housing market and on the financial viability of development”.

While this might sound reasonable and straightforward, the concern is that these assessments will be done in a narrow and conventional way, and particularly to determine what compensation is needed to make the developers “whole” again when providing affordable housing.

The key problem is this: because municipalities have only limited resources, requiring them to pay compensation is very likely to restrict the productivity of their IZ programs.
In other words, they will have to seriously reduce the number of units provided and/or the depth of affordability achieved in order to work within their resources.

The remainder of this paper addresses this issue by explaining that IZ programs can and should be designed in a way that they are not dependent upon compensation, and in any case, that compensation is not needed because the cost burden associated with affordable housing is not borne by the developers.

Experience in the US

The experience in the US clearly shows that compensation is not essential for having effective IZ programs. In other words, under the appropriate conditions, these programs can be productive without compensating the developers for the affordable housing.

This conclusion is recognized by a recent ULI report that has been touted by the development industry. That report states that “in very strong development environments (substantial amounts of new construction and rehabilitation, steady rent and price growth, low vacancy rates), IZ policies can yield development new workforce housing units without subsidy or other development incentives from the local jurisdiction”(Williams 2016).  Needless to say, all of above conditions apply in the City of Toronto.

The evidence in support of this conclusion is convincing, but needs some explaining.  In summary, it is based on these key points:

1)  While it is true that compensation is widely provided, it is not used in all mandatory programs. There are many of these programs that produce affordable housing without compensation. This, by itself, is clear evidence that compensation is not always needed.

2)   In most mandatory programs where compensation is offered, it is most typically provided through a fixed and limited set of regulatory concessions. These might include relaxed development regulations (for density, height, setbacks, parking, and others), waived fees and charges, and/or fast-tracked approvals.

These concessions are best seen as token payments. They are offered not as compensation, but mainly in recognition that municipalities should not be adding to the costs of providing affordable housing at same time as asking developers to deliver housing at a lower price.

In any case, the value of this relief is relatively small. It does not fully cover the cost burden of the affordable housing. As they are given on the same basis to all developments, they certainly are not calibrated to meet the needs of any particular development, nor any prescribed standard (like a 40% contribution).

There also is a downside to many of the most common concessions, and this in turn raises the question of how appropriate they are. For example, the waiving of fees could reduce service levels, or add the fees paid by others. The use of density bonuses could result in bad planning by approving higher density where not appropriate. The fast-track approvals for some applicants could cause delays for others.

3)  While some of these programs offer other forms of compensation, these are provided almost entirely in these two limited and targeted ways:

•   In all voluntary (or incentive-based) programs where, unlike in mandatory programs, municipalities must fully compensate developers for the affordable housing in order to secure their participation. But, while once widely used, these programs are used less and less because they are not productive.

•  In negotiated one-off deals where municipalities offer supplementary assistance in selected (often to non-profit developments) to secure greater affordability than provided under the standard and fixed rules. But, this practice occurs in a relatively small portion of the total IZ developments.

Among the additional forms of compensation provided in these cases are financial assistance like cash subsidies, property tax relief, and below-market loans. But it is important to note that these are rarely (if ever) provided under the standard and fixed provisions in the mandatory programs.

“Passing back to the land”

If the municipalities pay for none or only some of the cost burden associated with the inclusionary units, the question remains about who pays.

Over the last few years, there has been a growing understanding and recognition that the cost of the affordable housing under the appropriate conditions in IZ programs is “passed back to the land”. In other words, that cost will be substantially or entirely reflected in the lower price the developers are willing to pay for land.

Developers typically assess the value of the land before making a purchase. To do so, they determine the potential revenue that can be obtained by one or more development schemes. From that they deduct the projected costs of development (for construction, loans, fees and so on) as well as their anticipated profit (or return on investment). In this process, the affordable housing obligation is treated as just another cost. The price that then can be paid for the land is the residual value left after the total costs are deducted from the revenue.

Mandatory programs, unlike voluntary ones, enable this process by fixing the affordable housing obligation ahead of time, so it is known by all potential purchasers when bidding for the land. This stands in contrast with the s37 provisions, through which the value the land cannot be reliably determined because the community benefits are negotiated during the approval process and well after purchase.

The current literature contains many references confirming this process from acknowledged IZ authorities:

• David Rosen (2016): “Regulation and development impact fees or residential development that increase the costs of development, including housing standards, will ultimately be passed through to the land owner in the form of reduced land prices.”

• Rick Jacobus (2015): “When a city imposes inclusionary housing requirements, … land prices will fall to absorb the costs of the inclusionary housing requirements.”

• Nico Calavita and Alan Mallach (2009): “There is little doubt that there are costs associated with complying with a municipality’s inclusionary requirement. … There seems to be agreement in the literature that in the long run … most of these costs will be passed backward to the owners of land.”

• Douglas Porter (2004): “Economists tend to argue that, in the long run, developers of projects subject to special development costs (such as impact fees and inclusionary requirements) will lower prices for developable land, since housing must be produced at competitive prices and rents the market will bear.”

• Nicholas Brunick (2003): “Basic economic theory suggests that an inclusionary set-aside, without providing cost offsets or incentives to cover the incremental cost of producing the affordable units, would cause developers to … pay less for land. … most of the economic literature indicates … that developers will most likely … bargain for a lower land price in order to profitably develop the housing. Thus, the theoretical incidence of an inclusionary zoning program (without sufficient cost offsets or incentives) over time, would be born by owners of land … (who) might see a reduced rate of appreciation in the values of their land over time. However, this moderate reduction in a rising real estate market is not likely to deprive these owners of earning a still, very healthy return on their investment.”

• Alan Mallach (1984): “There seems to be agreement in the literature that in the long run … most of the costs [of the affordable housing] will be passed backward to the owners of land.”

This process should be considered fair and reasonable. Landowners obtain windfall gains – often enormous – due to rapidly rising land values that they have done nothing to create. On the other hand, municipalities do have a major role in creating those values through infrastructure investments and planning decisions. So, municipalities should be able to capture some of that gain, at least to the extent they have had a hand in creating it.

What this means for compensation

If the developers pass the cost burden back to landowners in this way, then it means they do not absorb the cost of providing the affordable housing. And so, municipalities should not be obliged to provide compensation to the developers. Providing compensation in these circumstances does not assist the provision of affordable housing, but rather mainly serves to sustain high land prices and add to the windfall gains of the landowners.

It bears repeating that municipalities have limited resources to provide for this assistance. If required, it would seriously hamper the output of these programs.

Municipalities should be looking to design their basic programs in a way that most developments would be required to provide a standard and fixed obligation while receiving no or little compensation. At most, out of fairness, municipalities should only consider offering regulatory relief to these developments.

Their limited resources, rather than being spread thinly over many developments, should be focussed on where they can have the greatest impact. That means they should be offered to selected developments where deeper affordability can be negotiated in exchange for the compensation.

In this context, the financial assessments of these programs should be devoted to determining, not what compensation is needed to make the developers “whole” again, but what are the limits to driving the costs back to the land and capturing inflated land values for a public purpose.

References

Dave Wilkes: “Inclusionary zoning plans are all take and no give”; Toronto Star; 18 August 2018.

Stockton Williams, et al: “The Economics of Inclusionary Development”, The Urban Land Institute and Terwillinger Center for Housing, 2016.

Nicholas Brunick: “The Impact of Inclusionary Zoning on Development”; Business and Professional People for the Public Interest; 2003.

Nico Calavita and Alan Mallach: “Inclusionary Housing, Incentives, and Land Value Recapture”; Land Lines, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy; January 2009.

David Paul Rosen & Associates: “Inclusionary Housing Study for the City of Portand”; November 2016.

Rick Jacobus: “ Inclusionary Housing – Creating and Maintaining Equitable Communities”; National Community Land Trust Network, Cornerstone Partnership and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy; 2015.

Douglas R. Porter: “Inclusionary Zoning for Affordable Housing”; Urban Land Institute, 2004.

Alan Mallach: “Inclusionary Housing Programs: Policies and Practices”; Center for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers University, 1984.

Richard Drdla
18 March 2019

Equity Sharing

The affordable units provided by IZ are subject to various controls to protect the long-term affordability of the units. The following addresses one of the key aspects of those controls: how the maximum price and income limits are set for the resale of the affordable ownership units.

The principal purpose of these particular controls is to ensure that the public stake in this housing is never lost. This refers to the value of the price reduction that has been engineered by these programs – or more specifically, the current difference between the initial market value of the unit and the initial permitted affordable selling price but as adjusted to the time of the resale.

In effect, under these controls, when an affordable unit is resold within the control period (now typically 30 or more years), it can be resold only at or below the permitted price and to a corresponding income-eligible household of the same size. Units sold after the control period can be sold on the open market, but the home seller only receives the current value of the permitted sales price, while the remainder of the value goes to the municipality for re-investment in affordable housing.

These controls are also affected by another consideration. All of the affordable ownership programs attempt to provide the owners with some reasonable share of the equity gain whenever the units are resold. This equity sharing is considered necessary to promote the proper upkeep of the unit, and also to help the owners to sell and move on when they want.

These two considerations are somewhat in conflict, and this leads to two different equity-sharing approaches that will be noted shortly.

Some of the programs set the limits in terms of price and others in terms of income. But they come to the same thing because one can be readily converted to the other using the current loan-to-income ratios determined by the prevailing mortgage interest rates and related factors. This is important because the programs in a sense must operate in two languages: the developers are most concerned about price and not income, and policymakers about income and not price.

(Note: the PPS definition does not treat them as interchangeable, and that is just one of the many unnecessary complications raised by this flawed definition.)

The resale price and/or income limits are set according to an index or formula registered in the title of the affordable unit when first sold, and then passed from owner to owner whenever resold. This same index or formula is used for the resales within and after the control period. As already noted, the only difference is where the public stake goes; it is either locked into the price of the unit, or it goes to the municipality.

There might be as many as a dozen indices or formulas that have been used to set the permitted resale price in affordable ownership programs in the US and Canada. For example, these include the CPI, a fixed percentage, and a fixed percentage with a cap. Many have been found wanting because of the skewed results that can occur when used over a long term.

Two of these make the most sense, and have used in the great majority of the affordable ownership programs. One is price-based and the other income-based.

The income-based approach uses the local median income as the index. So, for example, if the developers were required to sell the unit initially at a price affordable to a household at 80% of local median income, that unit can be resold to another household of a corresponding size at 80% of the median income as adjusted over time. The US government facilitates this approach by annually providing the median income for each household size for every jurisdiction in the country.

(Note: the income data needed to use this approach is not available. To be more specific, what is lacking is median income data for every jurisdiction that is updated annually and broken down by household size.)

The price-based approach uses average market price as the index. So, for example, if the unit was initially sold at 75% of the average market price, the homeowner can resell it only at 75% of the new market price current at the time of resale.

Two approaches lead to different equity-sharing arrangements, which serve two different policy objectives. The homeowners share in the price-based approach are likely to be much lower than the income-based because incomes generally have risen at a much lower rate than prices. Nevertheless, nearly all IZ programs use this approach because their objective is to provide and maintain affordable housing over the long term. Strictly speaking, this can only be done by ensuring the housing continues to go to households at the same income level.

The price-based approach, on the other hand, is used in programs where the emphasis is on using homeownership as a way of building household wealth and financial security. Notably, Habitat for Humanity takes this approach. Under this approach, the affordability of the units from an income viewpoint will steadily erode at each resale, but the price will always remain below the full market price.

The duration of home ownership is not relevant in these controls. For example, homeowners are not required to own the unit for (say) five or more years as a protection against windfall gains. Under these controls, the unit could be flipped the day after purchase because no special or unearned benefit will go to the seller.

The programs do not guarantee the permitted sales price; they only put a cap on it. If there is a downturn in the housing market, or if the housing is not maintained, the affordable homeowner will suffer the consequences like any conventional homeowner.

RD  22Feb2018

Myths

A number of myths continue to be associated with IZ, although there is no evidence to support them. These myths serve to cloud and confuse the debate on how best to design these programs.

As will be seen, many of these myths deal in one way or another with the cost burden associated with providing the affordable housing.

IZ is a “partnership”

This term is frequently used by the development industry in Ontario. It is used to suggest that the other levels of government, particularly the municipalities, must somehow have “skin in the game” – that is, contribute financially toward the affordable housing.

This is a made-in-Ontario concoction. No reference to either this term or the notion is found anywhere in the US with regard to IZ.

To the contrary, IZ programs in the US have been designed for the most part to operate with little or no financial support from the municipalities. Indeed, these programs were designed this way because the municipalities in the US, like those in Ontario, lacked the financial resources needed to provide this support.

The programs also are designed to operate independently from state-level programs. States are typically involved only when they provide financial assistance to secure affordable housing at a deeper level of affordability than achieved by the IZ programs on their own.

IZ raises housing prices for the market homebuyers

IZ is often described as driving up the price of housing for other homebuyers, either generally across the community or more specifically in the same development. This is said to happen because the developers will pass on the cost of the affordable housing to the other buyers.

But developers cannot hike house prices in this way. The market as a whole sets the price of housing, and not the individual developers. And it is reasonable to expect that developers are already selling at the highest possible price. So, they cannot raise the price to cover the affordable housing obligation or any other cost increase.

There are two authoritative studies coming out of the US that clearly support this position. More specifically, the studies show that the price of housing in municipalities with IZ programs is virtually the same of that in comparable municipalities without these programs.

Developers must absorb the cost burden of the affordable units

If the developers cannot pass the cost burden onto the market homebuyers, so the argument goes, then the developers must absorb the cost by taking a hit on their profits.

The possibility that the developers will accept any significant reduction in profits is remote. The more likely response is that the developers will postpone the development until the market conditions favour going ahead.

In any case, IZ programs are not designed with the expectation that the developers will absorb this cost. These programs intentionally fix the affordable housing obligation so that the developers can take into account the associated cost when bidding to purchase land for development. In this way, the cost associated with the affordable housing will be “passed back to the land” – that is, seen in the form of reduced land prices.

IZ depends upon concessions

While most IZ programs do provide concessions, the value of these concessions and rationale behind them is often misrepresented.

The concessions offered by IZ typically are related to the development requirements and approval process. They principally include waivers of development-associated fees and relaxation of various development regulations. As noted earlier, they certainly do not include financial subsidies.

These concessions are offered by the municipalities for a simple reason: they consider it unfair or inappropriate for them to be adding to the cost of affordable housing, while at the same time requiring the developers to reduce the price of that housing. So they do what they reasonably can to eliminate those costs.

It is notable that these concessions generally remain fixed over time, and are granted uniformly to all eligible developments. They certainly are not adjusted to meet any prescribed standard nor to satisfy any viability criteria relevant to any particular development.

The value of these concessions is also relatively modest. They typically represent no more than a small fraction of the price write-down associated with the affordable housing. They are determined by what the municipality can reasonably give and not by what might be required to sustain by any development.

Here is a final important point. While it is true that most programs do provide these concessions, there are many that do not. That these programs can produce affordable housing in the absence of concessions is proof by itself that they are not needed to make IZ work.

IZ works only with up-zoning

Under this thesis, up-zoning is necessary because the increased density allowed by the up-zoning is seen as a necessary way of paying for the affordable housing.

The experience in the US does not support this. The vast majority of 500 or so programs there apply IZ to all approvals, including developments proceeding “as-of-right” with no density increase. It is only in the dozen or so “big city” programs that IZ is tied to up-zoning. This occurs, not because IZ needs up-zoning, but because virtually all development in those cities needs up-zoning.

IZ relies on density bonusing

Density bonusing refers to offering additional density to compensate developers for providing affordable housing. The additional density is automatically granted on some standard basis fixed in advance and applicable to all eligible developments.

Density bonusing is rooted in an old way of thinking about inclusionary zoning. It comes out of early programs, and especially the so-called incentive-based (or voluntary) programs. In these programs, the developers are asked to provide affordable housing, and so must be rewarded amply to secure their participation. (This approach is reflected in the continued use of the term ‘incentives’, although ‘concessions’ and ‘compensation’ are more suitable terms under mandatory programs.)
These programs have been proven to be ineffectual, and so they are no longer considered as useful vehicles for IZ. While they still do exist, they have lost all relevance for new programs.

There is another reason for the change in thinking. Density bonusing represents bad planning practice. This is because the affordable housing obligation is established first, and then the density increase automatically follows. In other words, this means that affordable housing trumps all other planning considerations with regard to the allocation of density.

Mandatory programs typically take the opposite approach. In these programs, the permitted density is first determined by appropriate planning grounds, and then the standard affordable housing obligation is applied.

This approach is used by all of the “big city” IZ programs, where up-zonings are prevalent. It is also the practice in the City of Toronto when applying s37: the appropriate density is first established and then the community benefits negotiated, not the other way around.

RD 2Mar2018

What makes an effective program?

The experience in the US shows that to be fully effective IZ programs should incorporate a number of key aspects.  These aspects deal with how the rules in IZ programs should be framed and approached rather than with what specifically should be in them. (The latter is addressed in an introductory way in this website in A Guide to Developing Inclusionary Housing Programs.)

1)    Make the programs mandatory

First and foremost, the programs should be mandatory – that is, they should require the developers to provide affordable housing as a condition of obtaining a development approval.

Voluntary (otherwise called incentive-based or optional) programs have been proven to be far less effective in producing affordable housing. Developers have shown little interest in voluntarily providing that housing even in exchange for incentives. As a consequence, voluntary are no longer considered to be a credible option.

Municipalities also should be aware of a crucial difference between the two. In voluntary programs, the municipalities will be expected to provide sufficient compensation to make the developers “whole” again – that is, to cover the cost burden associated with the affordable housing. In well-designed mandatory programs, municipalities will not have that responsibility, for the cost burden can be passed back to the land.

2)    Apply the obligation as universally as possible

In order to achieve the greatest output, the affordable housing obligation should fall on as many developments as possible. These should include developments proceeding as-of-right, as well as those getting a rezoning. Also, they should include small developments because they typically represent a significant proportion of the total housing production.

Applying the obligation as widely as possible is also important for another reason: it is necessary if all developers are to be treated consistently and fairly.

3)    Use fixed and non-negotiable rules

The rules should be fixed, non-negotiable and set out in advance. This applies most particularly to those rules determining the cost of the affordable housing obligation, and also the value of any concessions (if any) provided by the municipality.

Fixed rules are fundamental to mandatory programs, as there can be no mandatory obligation if it can be negotiated away. They also are important for treating all developers consistently and fairly, and for facilitating the approval process.

Finally, fixed rules crucially affect the need for compensation in the programs. When developers know the cost burden of the affordable housing obligation with certainty and ahead of time, they will offer correspondingly less for purchasing the land for development. In effect, this will reduce or eliminate the need for other compensation by passing the cost of the affordable housing back to the land.

4)    Target “below-market” housing

The programs should be directed at extending the affordability range of the housing currently being made available. They will serve little or no public purpose if they are used to produce more of what private developers are doing already. So, the programs should clearly target “below-market” housing – meaning housing provided at a price or rent below what the market is providing for the equivalent housing

5)    Allow enhanced provision through negotiation

The programs should be capable of taking advantage of, and even encouraging, opportunities to secure enhanced provision. Most developments can be expected to meet the minimum provision with no negotiation, and with no change to the required obligation nor the concessions (if any) offered. But there will be others willing to provide an enhanced provision – possibly through a larger number of affordable units and/or the units at a deeper level of affordability. To achieve, the programs will need to be open to negotiating compensation specific to the added costs associated with that enhanced provision, and to fostering partnerships with non-profit providers.

6)    Maintain affordability “permanently”

The affordability of the affordable units should be protected for a long period of time, if not permanently. Those protections should ensure the housing remains available at an affordable rent or price, and only to income-eligible households.

During that period, the units should not be sold in the open market, even if the value of affordable housing is recaptured, because the inclusionary benefits of the housing will be lost.

7      Provide flexibility but within limits

The regulations should provide some flexibility in how the affordability housing obligation is met – particularly, by allowing the use of cash-in-lieu payments and off-site development. Both of these are important and useful ways of producing a wider range of affordable housing types and/or housing at deeper levels of affordability. They also potentially have the added benefit of engaging the non-profit sector in producing that housing.

There is a downside to allowing unlimited access to these options. Many developers will take advantage of them, with the consequence that the benefits of inclusionary developments will not be achieved.

So, the options should be available only at the discretion of the municipality, and only then where they can be demonstrably shown to produce a greater public benefit than the on-site obligation. There could be still other limits, such as requiring these options to be used only on developments in close proximity to the originating development.

8)    Recognize the importance of growth

These programs depend upon harnessing market activity to provide affordable housing. They take a share of what the developers are otherwise building. Where there is little or no such activity, IZ by itself is not capable of producing much affordable housing.

As a consequence, it should be recognized that the programs work most readily in communities or areas facing sustained and strong growth. They work well there because the growth leads to rising land values that can be tapped to support the provision of affordable housing.

What is not necessarily needed – compensation

Compensation for the affordable housing is not necessarily needed in mandatory programs in order for them to be productive. This is shown by the many productive programs that provide no or only limited compensation.

Mandatory (unlike voluntary) programs can be designed so that cost burden is passed back to the land – that is, reflected in the purchase price offered for the land. This can be achieved by setting reasonable affordable housing obligations, and using fixed rules that establish the cost burden with some certainty in advance.

Most of these programs do offer compensation, but only mainly through concessions available through the regulatory process – such as, relaxed development standards (notably, increased density), fee waivers and fast-tracked approvals. These typically do not include cash subsidies, property tax abatement, nor state or federal assistance of any kind.

Density increases are the most effective and widely used of these regulatory concessions. They are particularly valuable because the economic benefit generated by additional density will be by itself sufficient to cover the cost burden of the affordable units.

In most cases, however, that compensation can be best described as being no more than notional or token. The amounts are arbitrarily set and not related to the cost burden. They are based on what the municipalities can readily provide, and not what they need to provide. Once set, the compensation is seldom adjusted, although the cost burden changes over time and project-by-project.

There is certainly no evidence – whether in their ordinances or actions – that the municipalities in mandatory programs have ever assumed any obligation to make the developer “whole” again, or even to cover the cost burden in any calibrated or substantial way.

Compensation is provided the most in particular circumstances – namely, where the developments provide an enhanced provision beyond the minimum obligation. To do this, these developments need to be offered incentives covering the added costs specifically due to that enhanced provision. Because they are often negotiated on a one-off basis, this leads to much wider range of compensation being used than normally associated with these programs.

Density Bonusing

Density bonusing when used in inclusionary zoning (IZ) is a practice through which municipalities offer developers additional residential density (or development rights) in return for providing affordable housing.

In IZ programs the bonuses are generally are offered under non-negotiable rules fixed in advance. They are made available to all or most developments, although the permitted increase typically is adjusted according to the base density.

In many programs, particularly in early suburban communities, density bonusing is offered under a simple formulation: the permitted as-of-right base density is increased by one market unit for every affordable unit provided. In these cases, the extra density is compensation for the affordable housing.

In other programs, the increased density is only for developments providing additional affordable housing on top of the affordable units required by the base zoning. In these cases, the density bonus is an inducement for developers to provide additional affordable housing.

Most programs also typically include provisions to protect the local residents from excessive development. The municipalities place a limit (generally, somewhere between 10% and 25%) on the additional density that can be is granted as-of-right and/or make the density increase subject to local public review and approval.

Incidence

Density bonusing is widely used in IZ. A number of surveys indicate that it is used in large majority of programs, but these surveys are not adequate in revealing some key differences (Porter 2004, CCRH 2003, Schuetz 2009 and IHI 2010).

These surveys do not distinguish between mandatory and voluntary programs. All voluntary programs are most likely to offer density bonusing because they rely on providing fulsome compensation as a way of attracting the developers’ participation. As a consequence, if the mandatory programs could be separated out, they would show a much lower incidence of density bonusing.

The surveys also do not distinguish between rezoning and density bonusing (see next section). Most, if not all, IZ programs in major cities rely on conventional upzoning rather than density bonusing to secure affordable housing. This is because most developments in these cities need a re-zoning, which would predominate over density bonusing in the increased density permitted and affordable housing produced.

Experience in Toronto

In the 80’s, Toronto had successful but short-lived density bonusing program for office developments. It took cash in return for allowing higher densities, and then used that cash for building affordable housing. Although the program raised millions, it was closed down after pushback from the public, which considered this as selling development rights, and also allowing for office towers that were too tall.

Since then, the City has taken the position that allocating density must be based in the first place on “good planning”. This principle is applied when administering s37, which thereby relies on upzoning and not density bonusing.

Density Bonusing vs Upzoning

Density increases can be used in IZ to provide affordable housing through two processes: density bonusing and upzoning. The two are too often conflated, but are fundamentally different. They reflect different approaches toward how the density increase is determined, whether compensation is needed, and how the cost burden associated with the affordable housing is absorbed.

In conventional upzoning, the permitted density limits are determined development-by-development on the basis of planning grounds. The need for affordable housing is not a factor in that determination. In this case, sound planning prevails over affordable housing needs.

In this process, the affordable housing is seen as an obligation that all developers have. The cost burden of that housing is absorbed by the increase in land values resulting from the permitted density increase.

In the case of density bonusing, affordable housing goes ahead of planning. The need for affordable housing influences what density is permitted.

The increased density under density bonusing is seen as compensation to the developers for the cost burden associated with the affordable housing. Providing increased density in this way means the cost burden is not passed back to the land.

Summary of Issues

The use of density bonusing in IZ can be questioned for at least three significant reasons:

1. It potentially distorts the planning process. More specifically, it could automatically allow development exceeding what would be warranted by good planning grounds. In turn, this could serve to spark a public backlash against particular developments, and possibly even against IZ more generally.

2. It supports the argument that developers need compensation. In other words, developers must be paid for providing affordable housing rather than having an obligation to provide it. But developers do not need compensation because they are able to pass the costs of the affordable housing back to the landowners.

3. It has a limited role in a dynamic market like that in the City of Toronto. Most developments here will required rezoning that will provide higher density increases than that allowed under density bonusing. So, rezoning will override density bonusing in these circumstances.

References

Innovative Housing Institute: “Inclusionary Housing Survey – Measures of Effectiveness”; Nov 2010.

Douglas R. Porter: “Inclusionary Zoning for Affordable Housing”; Urban Land Institute, 2004.

Inclusionary Housing in California: 30 Years of Innovation; Non-Profit Housing Association of Northern California & California Coalition for Rural Housing; July 2003.

Jenny Schuetz et al: “31 Flavours of Inclusionary Zoning”; Journal of the American Planning Association; Autumn 2009.

 

Richard Drdla
28 March 2019

Who Pays?

Who pays for the affordable housing provided under inclusionary zoning is a key question.  The provision does not come free. The requirement for developers to provide housing at less than its full market value creates a cost burden that must be absorbed somehow in the development process.

Knowing who pays this cost burden is fundamental to understanding how IZ works, and also how to create programs that are both effective and as fair as possible to the developers.

The following examination is based upon what has happened with IZ programs in the US. It applies only to mandatory IZ programs, as voluntary (or incentive-based) programs set-up a different dynamic about who shoulders the burden.

The following deals in turn with each of the potential candidates for bearing the cost:
∙   the municipalities;
∙   the developers;
∙   the other homebuyers; and
∙   the landowners.

Municipalities

IZ is not reliant on funding either from the municipalities, or any other level of government, to provide the affordable housing. IZ can and does successfully operate without the use of any financial subsidies.

Having said that, it must be noted funding is used in particular circumstances, and this clearly represents the exception rather than the rule. To be more specific, the funding is always applied on top of what is required by the inclusionary regulations. In this way, the funding is used to reach an even lower level of affordability not possible by IZ alone.

What many municipalities – but no means all – do offer are regulatory concessions in exchange for the affordable housing. These typically allow for relaxing certain regulations (such as, those setting density and height limits, parking standards, and others), waiving fees and charges and using fast-tracked approvals. All of these concessions have an economic benefit, but they do not involve actual cash transfers.

In none of these programs, however, do these concessions make the developers “whole” again. In other words, they are not designed or calibrated to cover the full cost of providing the affordable housing. These concessions might be better seen as political cover, rather than anything close to financial remuneration.

Also, it is important to note there are also successful programs that offer no such concessions whatsoever. This indicates that the provision of the affordable housing under IZ is not dependent upon having these concessions, and so they are really not necessary at all.

There also is a downside to most or all of these concessions, and this in turn raises the question of how appropriate they are. For example, the waiving of fees could lead to a reduction in service levels, or higher fees for others. The use of density bonuses could result in bad planning by permitting higher density where not appropriate. The fast-track approvals for some could cause delays for others.

Finally, municipalities also typically offer cost savings through regulatory concessions of another type. Many allow for the affordable units to be smaller in size, and/or to be built with a lower standard of finish, fixtures or amenity generally. In other words, while the affordable units must still meet an acceptable minimum standard of construction, they need not match the market units in all of their costly aspects. These savings are most unlikely to cover the cost burden, but they do serve to soften that burden.

Developers

IZ programs do not expect nor rely upon the developers absorbing this cost burden. They are particularly not expected to take a loss to their profits. This is an assumption held by many, but one that is wrong.

It is unreasonable to expect developers to take the hit. Although the municipalities under IZ can mandate the provision of affordable housing as a condition of building, they have no power to compel developers to actually build anything. Developers can and will stop building when suffering an undue financial loss caused by the inclusionary requirements.

That the developers are not hit unreasonably by IZ is supported by clear empirical evidence showing that they do not stop production in municipalities with IZ. Two studies, done by non-partisan and university-based organizations (see  Furman and Smart Growth), both independently came to the same conclusion: namely, that IZ has had little or no impact on the overall production of housing in communities where it is used. Where IZ did have an impact – and this should be of no surprise – was on the size and type of housing being produced. In other words, IZ caused the production of smaller units and more multiple housing, but not a cut in the overall housing output.

From these findings, it can be reasonably inferred that developers are able to accommodate to the affordable housing requirements, and to continue to build without significant damage to their bottom lines, at least once these programs are fully established (see FOOTNOTE).

Homebuyers

Developers take the position that under IZ programs they will simply pass on the cost burden to the other buyers in any particular development. In turn, this will inevitably drive up the price of housing generally. As a consequence, these programs are asking the other homebuyers to subsidize the buyers of the affordable units.

The available empirical evidence does not support this position. Specifically, the authoritative studies noted above also examined the impact of IZ on housing prices and came to the same conclusion – namely, that IZ had little or no impact on housing prices. The house prices in municipalities with inclusionary requirements were virtually the same those in municipalities without. And, if there was any rice increase attributable to IZ, it was insignificant when compared with the overall increase in market prices felt in those places.

The reason for this is easy to understand. The price of housing is determined by the market as a whole – in a sort of tug-of-war between all developers and all buyers – and not by the individual developers on their own. Furthermore, developers can be reasonably expected already to be charging what they consider to be the full market value for their product. So, any cost burden imposed by IZ, or any of the myriad other potential cost increases, cannot be simply passed on to the other homebuyers in the form of higher prices.

(Developers sometimes express this position by saying that the homebuyer ultimately pays for everything – including not only the house itself, but also all of the government impositions like development charges, planning fees and inclusionary requirements. This is true but only to a point, because there also is a limit to what the homebuyer will bear and that is expressed through the market price. The job of the developers, if they want to stay in business, is to ensure that all of costs of development (plus their profits) somehow stay within that market price.)

Landowners

Economists that have examined IZ generally conclude the cost burden of these programs is mainly “passed back to the land” (see FOOTNOTE). By this they mean that any additional cost associated with IZ – or at least that not recovered in other ways like the regulatory concessions – results in the developers offering and paying less for the land. This outcome is not specific to IZ; it applies to all cost increases that cannot be included in the overall purchase price.

Before buying any piece of land for development, developers typically do some sort of financial analysis that involves comparing projected revenues with projected costs in one or more potential schemes. The inclusionary requirement is just another one of the many costs that needs to be quantified and considered in this analysis. Ultimately, it is the difference between the revenues and the costs (plus profits) that sets the ceiling for the price they can offer for the land.

Burdening landowners in this way should not be seen as unwarranted or unfair. Landowners in high growth areas especially have benefitted enormously from rising land values that are “unearned’ because they have done nothing to create them. On the other hand, municipalities have had a major role in creating those land values through their infrastructure investments, planning, decisions over land-use and other ways. So, IZ represents a way for municipalities to recover some part of that value that they helped to create but otherwise would fall into private hands.

Summary

The provision of affordable housing under IZ does impose a cost burden that must be absorbed somehow in the development process. That cost burden hits various players in this process in the following ways:

∙ The other homebuyers are not affected by these programs in any substantial way. Specifically, they do not see any significant increase to the house price they pay. While developers will certainly try to pass these costs on to the other homebuyers, their scope for doing this is very limited.

∙ The developers do not, nor are they expected to, absorb this cost. In particular, they do not typically take a profit loss under these programs.

∙ The municipalities generally offer regulatory concessions in these programs, but these concessions only provide limited and partial recompense. They do not offer financial subsidies for meeting the basic inclusionary requirement, but can use subsidies for meeting still deeper levels of affordability.

∙ The landowners must absorb most of the cost burden associated with these programs. Developers typically pass these costs back to the landowners by offering to pay less for the land.

FOOTNOTE

The foregoing analysis describes what happens in mature programs that have been in operation for some reasonable time. In these programs, the market dynamic will have adjusted so that the developers will have learned to limit what they offer for the land. So, in this way the cost burden will be passed back to the purchase price of the land.

There will be a different dynamic when these programs are first introduced. Developers already owning the land, and particularly those that have developments in the approval pipeline, will not be able to pass these costs back to the land. As a consequence, these developers could be hit by the costs of the inclusionary requirements.

To be fair to these developers, this problem will have to be addressed in some way – possibly, by phasing-in the provisions and/or delaying compliance until the adversely effected projects can be flushed through the approval pipeline.

Issues

In this section, various contentious issues related to inclusionary zoning are addressed.  These include the following: